- Dosage Comparison With Former Winners;
- Past Performance Indicators Of Late Speed; and
- Live Longshot Prices.
Note that I am not claiming any great insights and will be pleasantly surprised with a positive result.
Evaluating Gambles Using Dynamics outlines his idea of time averaging in contrast to ensemble averaging in a discussion of the St Petersburg Paradox. Note the parallels with volatility drag, median outcomes, and expected values!
As a long-distance, handicapper of Euro races, I look for events in England, France, and Ireland (Grade 1 Horse-Racing Countries) with a high degree of chaos (I have entropy scores for all race-types). From this initial list, I have selected seven race-types that I focus on exclusively. Because of the high level of uncertainty in these races, the market (wisdom of crowds) is a less successful predictor. With a Bayesian-based, Elo-Class algorithm, I generate my own performance figures. Using the performance figures for all entrants in a chosen race, I run a Monte-Carlo simulation of 1000 races that automatically generates a realistic odds-line as final output. Critically, as long as there is at least one overlay (almost always) in the chosen race, I finally run a Haigh-like, Kelly-variant algorithm that selects the final contenders. (As I have stated elsewhere, this list may include both overlays and underlays).
Though not my discipline (National Hunt Racing), Cheltenham's four-day graded stakes meeting is an exception. Effectively, this is the Breeders Cup of jumps racing. Lacking the in-depth expertise required to handicap this form of thoroughbred racing, I seek to focus on novice races where historical knowledge is as informative as current form. To that end, the Supreme Novices Hurdle has many similarities to the Kentucky Derby - young horses, many attempting a graded stakes, championship race for the first-time with little form in the book. Using dosage analysis of the "in-the-money" finishers over the last ten years and ranking the current field against this metric to identify "live" outsiders, shortlisted two interesting contenders - Shaneshill (14/1) and Tell Us More (25/1). Though not necessarily the most likely winners, these two selections are the best matched to previous contenders on dosage and, therefore, worthy of punting in both the win and show markets!
Many sports trading problems yield to both an analytical and a numerical solution.
In the above example, the numerical solution (using Solver in Excel) to minimizing the difference between expected value and volatility drag over a sequence of similar bets equals the analytical solution (using Kelly) for the same sequence!
With multiple bets (illustration only) in a single win market, what is the equivalent single bet that best summarizes the overall position?
As the worst win-loss outcomes are to either win only the minimum profit or lose the total stake, then the most informative summary position is a combination of both scenarios.
Aaron Brown, author of The Poker Face Of Wall Street, makes a strong case for the negative impact of volatility drag on expected value with respect to the Kelly Criterion in the following posts:
* Short-Term Variance
* Risk Of Ruin And Kelly Betting
* Bankroll Performance Simulator
* Betting Strategy.
The above before and after illustrations show a worked example of setting stakes to match a zero difference between expected value and volatility drag.
As the Latin triple asserts: Scripsi, Exposui, Feci ("I wrote, I explained, I did"), the trading posts below are not ivory tower musings but are the product of real-world experiences, though obviously not in that order.
Nassim Taleb’s latest book, Antifragile: Things That Gain from Disorder, defines a new concept, Antifragility. Operationalizing this concept in the world of sports trading would mean creating an approach that is explicitly designed to benefit from market volatility. In other words, an antifragile trading system would be characterized by a procession of small losses periodically punctuated by large gains - for example, live longshots. However, nobel laureate Daniel Kahnemann, Thinking, Fast And Slow, would point out that the pain endured by a succession of small losses will not be emotionally compensated by an iteration-ending large gain. Obviously, most humans are too fragile to handle antifragility!
David Edelman, Quantitative Finance lecturer, handicapper, and author derives a sports trading version of the Sharpe Ratio on page 28 of "The Compleat Horseplayer".
SR = (ProbWin - (1 / DecimalOdds)) / Sqrt(ProbWin * (1 - ProbWin))
For example, with the following 'investments', A is judged to be slightly better than B in terms of expected return per unit of risk:
A: ProbWin = 45%, DecimalOdds = 2.60
SR = (0.45 - (1 / 2.6)) / Sqrt(0.45 * (1 - 0.45))
= 0.13142
B: ProbWin = 31%, DecimalOdds = 4.00
SR = (0.31 - (1 / 4.0)) / Sqrt(0.31 * (1 - 0.31))
= 0.12973
In various horse-racing jurisdictions (e.g. Australia, UK, Ireland, France), there is a very strong correlation between the winning rates of favorites and Benford's Law. In other words, favorites win approximately 30% of races, second favorites approximately 18% and third favorites approximately 12%. One could conceivably use this information to generate some tickets for Daily Double, Pick 3, 4, 5, or 6 exotic pools by using a random number generator and a "Benford distribution" of win rates. Though unscientific in validation, this method proved invaluable to me over the Breeders Cup weekend (given many upsets to expected outcomes)!
In 1979 [Studies in Intelligence, Vol. 23, No. 1 (Spring 1979)], a study of expert handicappers demonstrated an interesting interaction between information and confidence. There were two key findings. First, as soon as an experienced handicapper has the minimum information (seven plus or minus two variables) necessary to make an informed judgment, obtaining additional information generally does not improve the accuracy of his selections. Second, additional information does, however, lead the handicapper to become more confident in his judgments, to the point of overconfidence. It appears that handicappers have an imperfect understanding of what information they actually use in making judgments. They are unaware of the extent to which their judgments are determined by a few dominant factors, rather than by the systematic integration of all available information.
As ever, if the handicapper cannot find variables that account for sufficient variance in outcomes over and above that provided by market prices then he will not have an edge and will lose his bankroll.